Skip to main content

[Speech]Recent Economic and Financial Developments, and Monetary Policy

日本語

Speech at a Meeting with Business Leaders in Oita

Takehiro Sato
Member of the Policy Board
June 5, 2014

Contents

I.  Introduction

Thank you for giving me this opportunity to exchange views with people representing the political, economic, and financial arena of Oita Prefecture.  I would like to take this opportunity to express my sincere gratitude for your cooperation with the activities of the Bank of Japan's Oita Branch.

In today's speech, I will begin by focusing on economic and financial developments in Japan and abroad, as well as the Bank's recent monetary policy.  I will then touch briefly on the economy of Oita Prefecture.  Following my speech, I would like to hear your views on actual conditions in the local economy and on the Bank's conduct of monetary policy.

II.  Recent Economic and Financial Developments in Japan and Abroad

A.  Developments in Japan's Economic Activity and Prices following the Consumption Tax Hike

Regarding recent developments in Japan's economy, although statistics relating to production and sales for April 2014 indicate a reactionary decline in domestic private demand following the consumption tax hike, the economy seems to remain resilient as a trend.  It should be noted that (1) some sentiment indicators are weak, although this was expected, and (2) a reactionary decline in demand following the front-loaded increase prior to the tax hike is somewhat hard to gauge due to supply-side constraints.  Let me follow up on this latter point.  In the automobile industry, for example, it is considered that a production decrease as a whole caused by the decline in demand will come to a halt in the July-September quarter of 2014.  Nevertheless, according to anecdotal information, there are some concerns about a possible decline in that quarter and thereafter, because production for the April-June quarter is not expected to be much affected by the decline in demand following the front-loaded increase, as backlog orders from the January-March quarter had piled up due to supply-side constraints.  This suggests that we need to remain cautious about this decline in demand, although there are many views that recent developments have generally been as expected.  From a somewhat longer-term perspective, I consider the critical point to be the extent to which positive effects on the employment and income situation -- such as the recent rise in base pay -- will be able to offset negative effects of the decline in real disposable income that is caused by the tax hike.

In this regard, the recent employee income situation can be understood as follows.  On the one hand, the rate of increase in nominal wages has remained weak at around 0 percent on a year-on-year basis, given that scheduled cash earnings are depressed -- reflecting the recent rise in the number of non-regular employees whose working hours are relatively short -- despite the increases in non-scheduled cash earnings and special cash earnings.  On the other hand, the total number of employees is boosted by the increase in non-regular employees; consequently, nominal employee income -- which is calculated by multiplying nominal wages by the number of employees -- has been increasing moderately at around 1 percent on a year-on-year basis (Chart 1).  Considering that the recent movements toward raising base pay will likely increase scheduled cash earnings from this summer, and that a rise in base pay, should it be realized, will positively affect non-scheduled cash earnings and special cash earnings, it is natural to think that nominal employee income will increase at a somewhat accelerated pace.  In my view, with this employment and income situation acting as a tailwind, Japan's economy will remain resilient against the consumption tax hike.

The consumer price index (CPI) figures since the consumption tax hike show that, excluding the effects of the tax hike, the year-on-year rate of increase in the CPI for all items less fresh food, or the core CPI, was generally around the previous month's level, and this is also a supporting factor for the assessment of the underlying trend that I just mentioned (Chart 2).  Prior to the release of the CPI figures, there was a lot of conflicting anecdotal information -- such as price hikes exceeding the rise in consumption tax and price cuts through discount sales.  It turned out, however, that the rise in consumption tax alone has basically been passed on to consumers.  From another perspective, consumer demand can be regarded as having been resilient enough to accept the passing on of the rise in tax.  Japan's economy is expected to return to a moderate recovery trend from the summer, as the subsequent decline in demand following the front-loaded increase wanes.

B.  Understanding of Coexistence of the Weaker-than-Expected Economic Growth Rate and Higher-than-Expected Prices

Japan's economy has decelerated from a high annual growth rate of around 4 percent in the first half of 2013 to around 1 percent in the second half (Chart 3).  This is partly due to sluggish exports despite the yen's depreciation, but a significant increase in imports should also be noted.  Imports surged due to firm domestic demand as well as the front-loaded increase in demand prior to the consumption tax hike, thereby pushing down the headline GDP growth rate.  However, focusing on domestic demand excluding net external demand, the economy did not see much of a slowdown given that this demand kept growing at around 3 percent on an annual basis throughout the calendar year.  As GDP growth for the second half of 2013 was weaker than expected, this will have a smaller carry-over effect on GDP growth for fiscal 2014.  Partly reflecting this technical factor, the median of the Policy Board members' forecasts for 2014 presented in the April 2014 Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (hereafter the Outlook Report) was revised downward, and there was also a downward revision to forecasts for fiscal 2013.  However, the mechanism of economic recovery will be maintained in a situation where exports recover and domestic demand remains resilient as a trend (Chart 4).  Regarding the April-June quarter of 2014, the contribution of net external demand to GDP growth is expected to turn positive, reflecting a decline in imports, and this will in turn act as a buffer against a decline in domestic private demand.  As I will describe shortly, recovery of overseas economies -- especially the U.S. economy, which is getting over the effects of the unusually severe winter weather and has started to return to a recovery trend -- is expected to act as a tailwind for Japan's economy.

In the meantime, the core CPI for fiscal 2013, which was revised upward from the median of the Policy Board members' forecasts in the January 2014 interim assessment of the Outlook Report, registered 0.8 percent on a year-on-year basis.  The fundamental reason behind this upward revision to prices despite the downward revision to the GDP growth rate will be explained later.  In what follows, I highlight the role of imports in this context.

One factor contributing to the rise in the CPI is a rise in energy prices stemming from the yen's depreciation.  However, it is also the case that the year-on-year rate of increase in the CPI for all items less food and energy, or the core-core CPI, for April 2014 excluding the effects of the consumption tax hike registered 0.8 percent, which shows that prices other than those of energy have also been rising.  In terms of price hikes for items other than energy and related goods, I am focusing on the price changes in digital appliances (Chart 5). 1

The CPI for digital appliances has risen by around 30 percentage points, from the range of minus 22-23 percent for February 2012 to the range of 6-7 percent for February 2014 on a year-on-year basis.  This had an indispensable effect on the rise in the core-core CPI.  As the background to this, it can be pointed out that prices of digital appliances had fallen to the bottom and fierce price competition in the household electrical appliances industry came to an end.  It should not be overlooked that the halt in the price decline of digital appliances is attributable to the fact that prices of these products had become more susceptible to the effects of the yen's depreciation with the increased import penetration ratio.  A decline in competitiveness and pricing power in the industry in Japan can be pointed out as a reason behind such susceptibility.  However, the CPI for digital appliances became more or less flat on a year-on-year basis in the March-April period of 2014 excluding the effects of the consumption tax hike as the yen's depreciation paused, and the core-core CPI for the Ku-area of Tokyo in May declined by 0.2 percentage point from the previous month on the same basis.  The effects of the halt to the yen's depreciation trend on future developments in prices should be monitored carefully.

  1.  1  Digital appliances refer to the following CPI items: TV sets, mobile audio players, electronic dictionaries, video recorders, personal computers (desktop type), personal computers (note type), PC printers, digital cameras, and video cameras.

C.  Overseas Economic and Financial Developments

As I just mentioned, Japan's economy is expected to continue growing at a pace above its potential as a trend due to the ongoing firm domestic demand, while it will be affected by the front-loaded increase and subsequent decline in demand prior to and after the consumption tax hike.  The probability of this scenario will be enhanced by the moderate increase in exports led by the recovery of overseas economies, particularly advanced economies.  In this regard, recent developments in overseas economies will support Japan's economy through exports; for example, the U.S. economy has been recovering moderately, led by private demand, with the recovery becoming more widespread, and the euro area economy is also recovering moderately (Chart 6).

With regard to the U.S. economy, the pace of recovery will accelerate gradually, mainly in private consumption, as the improvement in households' balance sheets makes progress supported by the ongoing recovery trend of housing prices as a whole, and as the effects of fiscal drag fade.  These positive effects will likely continue spreading to firms' production activity, and thus the recovery trend of business fixed investment is likely to become more evident (Chart 7).  Of course, the Federal Reserve's (Fed's) policy developments and their subsequent effects on global financial markets should be monitored as downside risks.  In this regard, the end in autumn 2014 to the Fed's asset purchase program has broadly been incorporated into the markets at this point.  In addition, the statement by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has clarified the view that "it likely will be appropriate to maintain the current target range for the federal funds rate for a considerable time after the asset purchase program ends."  My understanding is that the Fed will communicate carefully with market participants in order to avoid bringing instability to financial markets.

Regarding the euro area economy, there are various adjustment pressures associated with the excess debt problems in the public and private sectors.  However, the economy is expected to continue recovering moderately supported by ongoing recovery in domestic demand, reflecting improvement in various economic entities' sentiment (Chart 8).

As just described, advanced economies are likely to recover moderately, led by the U.S. economy.  Meanwhile, emerging and commodity-exporting economies will likely continue to lack growth momentum for the time being, especially in those economies that are restraining aggregate demand, such as by raising interest rates.

Looking at the Chinese economy, domestic demand is likely to continue facing downside pressure amid ongoing progress in structural reforms.  However, since the authorities have formulated concrete policy measures to underpin economic activity and external demand is expected to continue picking up, the economy is likely to maintain stable growth in general at around the current pace.

From a somewhat longer-term perspective, however, there are concerns about the Chinese economy due to factors such as demographic changes (Chart 9).  Labor supply and demand conditions seem to be tight, although the growth rate has fallen from double digits to the range of 7-8 percent.  This implies the possibility that China's potential growth rate is declining considerably.  While the authorities have set the growth target at around 7.5 percent, some of them have said that some downward deviation from 7.5 percent is within the target range.  It is better to take a conservative view that China's growth rate is likely to be around 7.5 percent at its highest, despite the government's measures to underpin economic activity.

D.  Risks to Overseas Economies

The outlook for overseas economies that I have explained is subject to both upside and downside risks.  Geopolitical risks such as the recent situation in Ukraine should be carefully monitored in the short run.  In addition, I am personally concerned about the possibility of a disinflationary trend and decline in potential growth rates in Europe and the United States in the medium to long run (Chart 10).

The euro area in particular should be carefully monitored as the disinflationary trend might be prolonged, mainly in peripheral countries.  Several peripheral countries in particular are expected to continue facing downward pressure on wages in order to retain competitiveness under the appreciation of the euro, and the European Commission and the European Central Bank (ECB) have revised down their inflation forecasts for both this year and the next.

Medium- to long-term inflation expectations both in Europe and the United States have been stable at around 2 percent, which is one of the reasons why the policy authorities in the euro area have taken the view that it will not enter stagnant deflation like Japan (Chart 11).  However, Japan's experience suggests the possibility that low inflation continuing for a long time changed people's inflation expectations in a backward-looking manner, and thus medium- to long-term inflation expectations also lowered adaptively.  In fact, as the disinflationary trend continues, short- and medium-term inflation expectations by economic entities and the markets have already started to decline somewhat in the euro area as well.

If the stability in medium- to long-term inflation expectations is undermined, various policy actions are expected to be taken.  The ECB has already revealed its policy stance that it will not hesitate to make use of unconventional measures to address the risk of prolonged disinflation, and I therefore am keeping a watchful eye on its future conduct of monetary policy.  It should also continue to be noted that the financial system is still somewhat fragile in the euro area.

In the United States, deflationary concerns have not been observed so far, and instead short-term inflation expectations in the private sector have been revised upward.  However, the inflation rate has recently been lower than the Fed's forecast, partly reflecting the stable energy prices brought about by the shale revolution.  Therefore, I feel it necessary to take into account the risk that the inflation rate will remain lower than the optimal level from a somewhat longer-term perspective.

It also should be noted that an argument that raises concerns about secular stagnation of the global economy has attracted somewhat more attention.  Lawrence Summers, for example, has argued that there is a possibility that the level of equilibrium real interest rate -- or, the natural rate of interest -- that is consistent with full employment has declined to the range of minus 2-3 percent in the United States since the late 2000s, as there has not been excess demand in the economy before and after the financial crisis, and because prices have been stable, with the actual GDP rate continuing to be far below the potential one. 2  The argument regarding secular stagnation after the crisis seems reasonable, considering the experience in Japan -- namely, that it continued to be difficult to boost demand, in part reflecting the financial crisis in the late 1990s and demographic changes since the 2000s.  Paul Krugman previously noted that Japan's equilibrium real interest rate had temporarily declined to around minus 4 percent. 3  What is new about the arguments of Summers is that the equilibrium real interest rate has been declining for a long time, not temporarily, on a global scale, against the background of, for example, excess savings in countries with a current account surplus and the decrease in the nominal investment amount arising from declining capital goods prices.

Leaving aside the question of whether the equilibrium real interest rate has actually been declining in negative territory for a long time, it seems plausible that growth momentum in the global economy has declined somewhat more than in a typical cyclical pattern, reflecting the prolonged downturn in demand, the deceleration in labor input, and the slowdown in technological innovation.  As a background to this, for example, the forecast for global growth by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) has been consistently revised down, and growth rates in emerging economies are far lower than those before the Lehman shock.  Assuming that the equilibrium real interest rate has declined due in part to the slowdown in the potential growth rate, and that weak growth in demand has started to become chronic in this situation, it becomes easier to understand the current disinflationary trend in advanced economies and the downward trend in inflation rates in emerging economies.

However, we should avoid making a hasty conclusion.  It is not easy to grasp the situation of the potential growth rate and the slack in the economy. 4  There are various arguments over whether the decline in the inflation rate is solely attributable to a cyclical factor or is rooted in a structural one, as described earlier.  It also is often difficult to distinguish a cyclical factor from a structural one.  If the potential inflation rate has not declined much, the current disinflationary trend could simply reflect the slack in capital stock and in the labor market, and it is possible that disinflationary pressure will ease as the slack dissipates.  As just described, the inflation outlook and its implication for macroeconomic policy could change depending on how to understand the current potential growth rate.  Thus, I will continue to carefully monitor this matter.

  1.  2  For details, please view Lawrence Summers' recorded remarks at the Fourteenth Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference (Link to an external website) held by the IMF in November 2013.
  2.  3  See Paul Krugman, "It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 1998, pp.137-205.
  3.  4  There are many earlier studies on uncertainties regarding estimation of potential growth rates and slack in the economy.  See, for example, Athanasios Orphanides, "Monetary Policy Rules Based on Real-Time Data," American Economic Review, 91 (4), 2001, pp. 964-985.  For examples of such estimation in Japan and the United States, see, respectively, Takuji Fueki et al., "Measuring Potential Growth in Japan: Some Practical Caveats," Bank of Japan Review Series, No. 2010-E-1, 2010, and Mitsuhiro Osada et al., "Beikoku no Roudou Shijyou no Surakku nitsuite (The Slack in U.S. Labor Markets)," Bank of Japan Review Series, No. 2014-J-2, 2014 (available in Japanese).

III.  The Conduct of Monetary Policy for the Immediate Future

A.  Interim Review on Quantitative and Qualitative Monetary Easing

Fourteen months have passed since the Bank introduced quantitative and qualitative monetary easing (QQE) in April 2013.  Looking at economic and price developments over this period, as mentioned earlier, economic growth has turned out to be somewhat lower than the Bank's projection, due to developments in exports and imports, and prices have been higher than projected.  Economic and price developments so far have been in line with the Bank's projection on the whole.  Thus, the Bank summarized in the April 2014 Outlook Report that QQE has been exerting its intended effects.  The Bank's Policy Board has judged it appropriate to steadily pursue QQE under its current guidelines.

However, although prices are higher than projected, the transmission mechanism of QQE, such as progress in the so-called portfolio rebalancing and a rise in medium- to long-term inflation expectations, has not yet been observed to the extent the Bank initially intended.  Of course, I have no intention of denying that the mechanism is working.  In fact, some marginal changes have been observed; for example, financial institutions are gradually taking a more active risk-taking stance.  However, the current price hike seems to be affected not only by the yen's depreciation and the rise in energy prices but also by the fact that the economy -- mainly on the employment front -- is starting to reach the upper limit of supply capacity sooner than expected, as the economic recovery is led mainly by nonmanufacturing, for which labor productivity is lower than that in manufacturing.  In what follows, I explain this matter.

B.  Mechanism of Price Hikes

In the April 2014 Outlook Report, the mechanism of price hikes is explained as follows: the output gap, which shows the utilization of labor and capital, has been improving mainly on the labor front, reflecting firm domestic demand, which tends to have large stimulative effects on employment, and it appears to have reached around the past long-term average of about zero; in this situation, upward pressure on wages and prices due to the tightening of supply and demand conditions is likely to steadily increase.  Actually, the bottleneck caused by the labor shortage can be observed widely, and its effects are reflected in the hourly pay of non-regular employees such as part-time workers.  The effects of wage hikes easily penetrate prices, particularly in the services sector -- which is relatively labor intensive -- and such effects seem to have already appeared in services prices, such as for meals outside the home (Chart 5).

Let me note that there are various approaches to estimating the output gap, and estimates are subject to a margin of error.  However, in light of the overall macroeconomic information -- such as tightness of the current labor conditions and the reduction in excess production capacity shown in the March 2014 Tankan (Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan) -- it could be considered that the output gap, regardless of whether it has or has not reached about zero, has already narrowed to a considerable degree.  This narrowing seems to be affecting prices to some extent.  Nevertheless, it should be noted that this situation seems to reflect not only the demand-side pick-up but also supply-side constraints, and therefore attention needs to be paid to the possibility that the mechanism of economic and price recovery could be different from what the Bank initially aimed for.

In other words, it is possible that the potential growth rate of Japan's economy has declined, especially after the Lehman shock.  This is because manufacturers' stagnant fixed investment in Japan led to a slowdown in accumulation of capital stock, which in turn decreased labor productivity.  Tight labor conditions, due to the recovery led mainly by nonmanufacturing, seem to be affected by lower labor productivity in nonmanufacturing compared to manufacturing (Chart 12).

It is true that wage increases induced by tight labor conditions are a profit-squeezing factor and thus not preferable for firms.  If corporate profits are constrained by labor costs, business fixed investment will be restricted and stock prices will be affected, and consequently wage hikes will not be sustainable.  It is desirable to see wage increases that are in line with growth in labor productivity.  In this regard, in achieving sustainable wage increases, it is indispensable to have a boost in labor productivity in nonmanufacturing, such as through investment aimed at labor saving.  If such efforts toward improvement in labor productivity in nonmanufacturing feed back into manufacturing and a virtuous cycle in the overall economy is generated, the growth potential will be raised, thereby enhancing the probability of achieving the price stability target of 2 percent in the medium to long term.  Currently, in my view, people's perception of labor conditions is tighter than what is suggested by statistics, as labor shortages are being reported widely.  It can be considered that Japan's economy is at a critical point in terms of whether its growth will slow due to supply-side constraints or it steps up to a new stage of growth by leveraging such constraints as a driving force to further improve its labor productivity.

C.  Importance of Flexibility in the Conduct of Monetary Policy

When the price stability target was introduced in January 2013, the Bank clearly stipulated that the conduct of monetary policy has to be flexible by examining various risk factors, including those related to financial imbalances, in addition to the assessment of current developments and outlook for economic activity and prices, from the perspective of achieving sustainable growth with price stability.

The importance of flexibility in monetary policy is what I have been focusing on to date.  Monetary policy requires long and variable time lags before its effects permeate the economy, and thereafter prices.  Therefore, to achieve a sustainable growth path in the context of price stability, monetary policy needs to be flexible, taking into account future prospects.  In other words, the Bank examines the current conditions and the outlook for economic activity and prices, and also analyzes various risk factors including the accumulation of financial imbalances.

In addition, the Bank clearly commits to continuing with QQE, aiming to achieve the price stability target of 2 percent, as long as it is necessary for maintaining that target in a stable manner.  In my understanding, the timeframe for "maintaining that target in a stable manner" should be assessed on a forecast basis.

In this regard, the price stability target is by no means a rigid and superficial framework that simply aims to raise the inflation rate to reach 2 percent temporarily.  Rather, it is a flexible and practical framework that accommodates the needs arising from economic developments.

As described in the minutes of the Monetary Policy Meeting held on April 30, 2014, my own view on the outlook for prices is somewhat more cautious than the majority view of the Bank's Policy Board members.  However, this does not mean that I am skeptical of QQE's effects, nor does it mean that I deny the effectiveness of the QQE's transmission mechanism.  My understanding is that the price stability target is not a framework that calls for the inflation rate to reach 2 percent with surgical precision, but rather that it represents a flexible policy framework in which some degree of latitude -- both upside and downside -- should be accommodated.  Based on this understanding, I see some flexibility with regard to the achievement of the 2 percent price stability target.

On this point, what the price stability target aims to achieve is not a situation in which only prices will rise.  Rather, it aims to achieve an environment in which the improvement of the overall economy results in higher wages and then higher prices in a well-balanced manner.  It is necessary to avoid any misunderstanding that the Bank has been solely pursuing a pick-up in prices without due attention to the economy.

Let me turn to price indicators that are referred to in assessing the achievement of the price stability target.  It is sometimes misunderstood that the degree of such achievement is merely assessed by using the core CPI, given that forecasts of the Policy Board members are made in terms of the CPI on this basis.  In fact, the price stability target is set based on the CPI for all items, not the core CPI.  However, this does not mean that the degree of achievement of the target is assessed only by using the CPI for all items.

To evaluate price developments, it is necessary to appropriately understand the underlying trend of price changes by excluding temporary destabilizing factors.  In doing so, the indicator that appropriately assesses price developments depends on each country's economic structure.  The Bank puts emphasis on the core CPI that excludes fresh food, which fluctuates largely due to such factors as the weather.  This CPI is used for Policy Board members' forecasts in the Outlook Report.  To understand the underlying trend in prices, however, a wide range of indicators should be monitored carefully while fully taking into account characteristics of each indicator.  Such indicators include not only the CPI for all items, the core CPI, and the core-core CPI, but also the CPI for all items less imputed rents -- which represents a concept similar to the cost of living -- as well as those relating to wages.  It is important to note that monetary policy is not tied to specific indicators (Chart 13).

D.  Developments in Long-Term Interest Rates

Next, I would like to talk about developments in long-term interest rates.  Market participants' price outlook has been lower than the Bank's baseline scenario to date, and as a matter of fact, long-term interest rates have been stable at low levels partly due to asset purchases by the Bank.  Future developments in long-term interest rates depend on market participants' economic and price outlook, but I am paying close attention to whether the price situation and nominal long-term interest rates will develop in a consistent manner in a situation where the rate of increase in the core CPI excluding the effects of the consumption tax hike has been around 1-1/4 percent on a year-on-year basis for six consecutive months.

Here, let me recap how QQE will work on nominal long-term interest rates through its transmission mechanism.  Nominal long-term interest rates combine two elements: one is the average of future short-term rates and the other is premiums (Chart 14).  Based on this understanding, the Bank has specified its forward guidance -- namely, that it will continue with the QQE, aiming to achieve the price stability target, as long as it is necessary for maintaining that target in a stable manner.  This in effect will exert downward pressure on the average of expected future short-term rates.  In addition, premiums will be prevented from widening through the Bank's massive purchases of JGBs with relatively longer maturities.  However, under such unconventional policy, nominal interest rates are likely to face upward pressure as the effects of the policy start to appear, preceding the improvement in the economy and prices.  Referring to the elements that I have just explained, expected future short-term rates are likely to rise if market participants judge that an exit from current easing policy is at hand.

In the case of a rise in nominal long-term interest rates, even when a central bank increases its purchases of government bonds, or otherwise is put under pressure to increase such purchases, in order to suppress the government's borrowing costs, the premiums might possibly rise if it is judged by market participants that the central bank's purchases will weaken fiscal discipline.  This is because, when the level of long-term interest rates is formulated, it is the market's judgment that matters rather than a central bank's intention.

These arguments are hypothetical and can be regarded as simply the result of brain storming at this point.  However, as the economy heads toward overcoming deflation, the effects will start to spread to long-term interest rates.  At that point, the Bank's monetary policy, including the process through which it will eventually exit from the current easing policy, should not be decided by giving consideration to fiscal sustainability, but instead be decided solely from the standpoint of achieving the 2 percent price stability target.  In that sense, I would like to reemphasize that the government's commitment to medium- to long-term fiscal consolidation plays an important role in ensuring the ultimate success of QQE.

IV.  Concluding Remarks: Economic Activity in Oita Prefecture

Economic activity in Oita Prefecture is somewhat more sluggish than that in Japan as a whole, which has been showing clear recovery.  The share of manufacturing in this prefecture is larger than that in the country overall.  Electronic parts and devices -- which face a decline in orders due to increased competition with foreign manufacturers and to sluggish sales of final products -- account for a large share of manufacturing in the prefecture.  Accordingly, the industrial production index for this prefecture has been below that for the whole country as a trend, albeit with some fluctuations due to the front-loaded increase in demand prior to the consumption tax hike (Chart 15).  Considering that Japan's current economic recovery is characterized as being led mainly by nonmanufacturing, the large share of manufacturing in the prefecture's industrial structure might be the reason for the sluggish recovery compared with that of the country as a whole.

It also should be noted that positive developments have been spreading.  Anecdotal information suggests that, although private consumption -- mainly apparel, high-end goods, furniture, and household electrical appliances -- has been affected by the reactionary decline in demand following the front-loaded increase prior to the consumption tax hike, the decline is not significant despite a larger-than-expected front-loaded increase in demand.  Private consumption is therefore likely to remain resilient in a situation where labor supply and demand conditions continue to improve.  Business fixed investment will likely expand significantly in nonmanufacturing, due, for example, to new construction of large distribution sites and to an extensive renovation of a new commercial complex, which will open at Kyushu Railway Company's Oita Station.  Such investment is also scheduled to start increasing in manufacturing owing to positive developments such as the establishment of new production lines for some new products, in addition to a rebound from the decline observed in fiscal 2013.

From the medium- to long-term perspective, it is encouraging that the private and public sectors are making joint efforts that make the most of regional characteristics.  I would like to give two examples.  First, joint efforts have been made in the field of renewable energy.  Oita Prefecture is a frontrunner in Japan in this field, being ranked first in terms of the self-sufficiency rate of such energy and taking second place in terms of the supply amount.  After the Great East Japan Earthquake, entry into the power generation business using renewable energy sources in the prefecture has become active, due in part to the introduction of the country's feed-in tariff scheme for renewable energy.  In particular, geothermal power generation business is very active in Oita Prefecture, which is rich in hot spring sources and daily inflow of water, both of which rank number one in Japan.  Substantial support for this power generation business is available; for example, the prefectural government and the private sector have jointly established a fund to encourage firms to start such business by utilizing the heat of hot springs.  Second, joint efforts have also been made in the field of tourism.  Oita Prefecture is rich in tourism resources, including some of the most popular hot spring sites in Japan, such as Beppu and Yufuin.  With a view to taking advantage of such resources, the prefecture formulated the "Tourism Strategies" in 2012 and is actively doing promotion both in Japan and abroad under the slogan "'OITA' The Best Onsen (Hot Spring) Area in Japan."  In addition, there have been events such as the start of operation in October 2013 of the super luxury sleeper cruise train called the Seven Stars in Kyushu, or Nanatsuboshi, and the extension of the Higashi-Kyushu Expressway in fiscal 2014.  These will likely promote an increase in the number of visitors.  I hope the economic activity in Oita Prefecture will become more active through these various joint efforts of the private and public sectors.