Skip to main content

[Speech]Wages and Prices: Past, Present, and FutureSpeech at the Meeting of Councillors of Keidanren (Japan Business Federation) in Tokyo

日本語

UEDA Kazuo
Governor of the Bank of Japan
December 25, 2023

Introduction

It is a great honor to have this opportunity to address such a distinguished gathering of business leaders in Japan today.

Last year in his speech at the Keidanren meeting, former Bank of Japan Governor Kuroda pointed out that we were "approaching a critical juncture in breaking out of the prolonged period of low inflation and low growth." Looking back on 2023, it was indeed a year that saw moves toward a transition. Japan's economy has turned to a moderate recovery, mainly reflecting the normalization of economic activity and a waning of supply-side constraints, and the output gap has improved to around 0 percent. Japan's inflation rate, measured in terms of the consumer price index (CPI), has continued to exceed 2 percent. This is mainly due to a pass-through of the past rise in import prices to consumer prices, but with economic improvement, some changes have been seen in firms' wage- and price-setting behavior. Given these changes, the likelihood of Japan's economy getting out of the low-inflation environment that it has been in over the past 25 years and achieving the Bank's price stability target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner seems to be gradually rising.

Today, I would like to talk about recent price and wage developments, which are closely related. In assessing the current situation of wages and prices and predicting their future, it is essential to consider the issue of why the situation in which wages and prices do not increase easily has continued to this day. Therefore, let me begin with reflections on the past.

I. The Past: Overview of and Background to the Low-Inflation Environment

Changes in the Wage and Price Situation in the Late 1990s

First, let me turn the clock back 25 years to the late 1990s. Wages and prices in Japan continued to rise, albeit slightly, until around the mid-1990s. In the late 1990s, the year-on-year rates of change turned 0 or negative (Chart 1).

Regarding changes seen in the late 1990s, not only did the aggregate rate of inflation fall to around 0 percent, but data at a more micro level show that the tendency of firms to keep prices unchanged had strengthened for many items to a considerable degree. It is natural for prices of individual items to rise and fall in accordance with their costs and demand; from the mid-1990s, however, the share of items for which prices were unchanged increased and the frequency of price revisions declined, especially for services in these two cases (Chart 2). Similarly, when it comes to wages, the practice of increasing base pay fell by the wayside at many firms. Wage growth slowed as, in addition to the fact that inflation declined, labor and management cooperated in prioritizing job retention under the difficult economic environment. These changes can be summarized as a shift from a state in which wages and prices move to one in which they do not. Although wage growth and price inflation also declined in the United States and Europe during this period, prices were still being revised to some extent, and there was no major shift toward a situation in which firms kept wages and prices unchanged.

Entrenchment of the Low-Inflation Environment

So, why did low inflation become entrenched in society and why did wages and prices stop moving in Japan? I think the basic background is that various downward pressures on wages and prices were operating for a long time.

In other words, the economic stagnation lasted for a prolonged period from the late 1990s, due to the protracted balance-sheet adjustment pressure following the collapse of the bubble economy and to Japan's financial crisis resulting from that collapse and the subsequent decline in the functioning of financial intermediation. In the mid-2000s, the economy finally began to recover in earnest and the output gap turned positive for a while (Chart 3). Thereafter, however, Japan underwent a series of large shocks, including the Global Financial Crisis and the Great East Japan Earthquake, and its economic activity and prices were thus pushed down again.

While Japan's economy intermittently came under strong downward pressure from the demand side, it should not be overlooked that structural changes, such as demographic changes and globalization, continued to push down wages and prices. The declining population likely pushed down expectations of growth in domestic demand and acted to restrain factors such as business fixed investment. In some respects, advances in globalization also exerted downward pressure on wages and prices. While the growth of emerging economies created new markets, it also intensified international competition. Price competition from low-priced imports had a large impact on Japan, mainly due to its industrial structure and geographic position. Moreover, analyses using firms' financial data suggest that, as firms' price competitiveness in product markets declined, it became difficult for them to add increases in costs, such as of raw materials, to selling prices, forcing them to hold down wages (Chart 4).1

Given the downward pressure on wages and prices, the Bank of Japan became the first central bank in the world to adopt unconventional monetary easing measures, such as the introduction of quantitative easing in the early 2000s, and endeavored to prevent, for example, the economy from falling into a marked slowdown, concern over financial system stability from growing, and prices from declining significantly. However, with short-term interest rates -- the main monetary policy tool -- having fallen to 0 percent, there was limited room for reducing interest rates, so the Bank could not sufficiently stimulate the economy and bring wage growth and price inflation back into clearly positive territory.

As the rates of change in wages and prices remained at around 0 percent, as just described, this may have gradually increased people's expectation that wages and prices would continue not to move. With customers keeping a keen eye on prices and given that competitors were unlikely to choose to raise prices, it was difficult for firms -- even if their costs had risen somewhat -- to opt to be the only ones to raise prices.2 As you may recall, there were even cases in which a price hike by a single firm made headlines. When not raising prices becomes the norm, the barriers to raising prices become even higher. In macroeconomics, the costs that firms incur when revising prices are called "menu costs." While the term menu costs originally comes from the costs that restaurants incur when changing the prices of their dishes, firms incur a variety of costs when actually raising prices, including explaining and negotiating price rises to and with customers. In Japan, in a situation where, for example, firms kept prices unchanged for a prolonged period and the know-how for raising prices was thus lost, menu costs may have become quite large, and this may have been one of the factors that led to the entrenchment of a state in which prices did not move. As it became the norm for wages and prices not to move, in the second half of the 2010s, increases in wages and prices remained small even as the output gap continued to be positive and labor market conditions became increasingly tight.

  1. Fukunaga, Kido, and Suita (2023) show that shocks originating abroad pushed down prices in Japan from the 1990s through the 2010s. Similarly, Aoki, Hogen, and Takatomi (2023) and Hogen et al. (2023) show that, under the severe competitive environment, Japanese firms' price markups shrank and downward pressure on wages intensified to make up for this.
    Fukunaga, I., Kido, Y., and Suita, K., "Japan's Inflation and Global Inflation Synchronization," mimeo (2023).
    Aoki, K., Hogen, Y., and Takatomi, K., "Price Markups and Wage Setting Behavior of Japanese Firms," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 23-E-5 (April 2023).
    Hogen, Y. et al., "Changes in the Global Economic Landscape and Issues for the Japanese Economy," mimeo (2023).
  2. In this context, Sasaki, Yamamoto, and Nakajima (2023) find that, in Japan, there is a nonlinearity in the impact (pass-through) of increases in firms' input costs on the rate of CPI inflation, depending on the size of cost increases. Moreover, using microdata from the Tankan (Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan), Ikeda et al. (2023) show that firms tend not to raise selling prices even if costs rise when their competitors do not raise prices.
    Sasaki, T., Yamamoto, H., and Nakajima, J., "Nonlinear Input Cost Pass-Through to Consumer Prices: A Threshold Approach," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 23-E-9 (May 2023).
    Ikeda, S. et al., "Firms' Recent Price-Setting Stance: Evidence from the Tankan," Bank of Japan Review Series, no. 23-E-2 (February 2023).

II. The Present: Changes in the Wage and Price Situation and the Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Global Upward Pressure on Prices

Next, let me turn the clock forward to the present. After the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic waned in 2021, inflation rose rapidly around the world. This was the result of a rapid recovery in demand following the normalization of economic activity, coupled with supply-side constraints, which were mainly due to supply-chain disruptions, and high commodity prices following Russia's invasion of Ukraine. In the United States and the euro area, year-on-year inflation rates at one point registered around 10 percent, and in Japan -- with the significant increase in the cost of imported raw materials being transmitted with a lag -- the inflation rate has continued to exceed 2 percent since spring last year. The shock of rising import prices has brought about a major change in firms' price-setting behavior, at least in the short term, as seen in the fact that even firms that had long kept their selling prices unchanged have raised them (Chart 5).

So, the question is whether the state in which wages and prices do not move has truly become a thing of the past. The first notable point is that the year-on-year rate of change in import prices, which have led the recent price rises, has been negative since around spring this year and that the rate of increase in producer prices has decelerated to around 0 percent recently. Looking at the CPI, the rates of increase in prices of goods such as food and daily necessities have started to decelerate. Given these developments, although it will take time, the effects of the past rise in import prices pushing up overall prices are likely to gradually wane.

Virtuous Cycle between Wages and Prices

As the impact of the rise in import prices wanes, an important issue in assessing whether wages and prices have started to move is whether the recent changes in firms' behavior will be sustained. The recent price rises are attributable to the unusual situation of the surge in import prices, and some argue that wages and prices will stop moving again if the impact of this surge wanes. However, I expect that this time around, Japan's economy will get out of the low-inflation environment and achieve a virtuous cycle between wages and prices.

In the past, there were times when moves to raise prices did not become widespread, as improving trends in the economy were cut short by declines in corporate profits and household income due to rising costs of imported raw materials. In contrast, during the current phase, demand has been underpinned by, for example, the government's economic measures and the Bank's continuation of monetary easing, thus providing support for achieving a virtuous cycle between wages and prices. A major difference from the past is that, in this situation, corporate profits have improved and set a record high.

Moreover, changes have also been seen in some of the factors that have exerted structural downward pressure on wages and prices thus far, such as demographic developments and globalization. It remains the case that the aging and declining population tends to act to curb growth expectations for domestic demand. However, the pace of increase in labor supply, especially among seniors, is projected to slow, in part because the baby boomer generation is approaching the age of 75, a level beyond which the labor force participation rate declines significantly (Chart 6). This is expected to act as a factor leading to higher wages. As for globalization, at least the environment in which competition from low-priced imports from abroad pushes down prices has started to change. From a somewhat long-term perspective, it is necessary to keep an eye on the possibility that supply-side shocks to prices are changing in frequency, persistence, and nature due to factors such as (1) moves toward strengthening supply chains and economic security in countries around the world, (2) firms' efforts toward addressing climate change, and (3) heightened awareness of other environmental, social, and governance issues, and that these changes are affecting the global price environment.

In fact, firms' price-setting stance and indicators of inflation expectations show that there has also been a change in the medium- to long-term outlook, and a view that changes in the wage and price situation are not temporary appears to be gradually becoming widespread. Firms have maintained their outlook for selling prices that prices will rise firmly over the medium term despite a decline in import prices. Similarly, indicators of medium- to long-term inflation expectations show that inflation expectations have risen moderately among all groups -- firms, households, and economists (Chart 7). Moreover, some firms reported that, having experienced a price hike for the first time in a long time, they will find it easier to negotiate price revisions in the future. This suggests that the menu costs I mentioned earlier may be getting smaller.

Key Points for the Future

In sum, the likelihood of Japan's economy getting out of the low-inflation environment and achieving the price stability target is gradually rising. However, I should note that this likelihood is still not sufficiently high at this point. Since there are extremely high uncertainties surrounding economic activity and prices at home and abroad, it is necessary to examine how firms' wage- and price-setting behavior will change.

In terms of wage setting, the key point is whether wages will continue to rise markedly in next year's annual spring labor-management wage negotiations. Looking at the recent situation surrounding wages, labor market conditions have tightened even relative to last year (Chart 8). Corporate profits, which are the source of wage hikes, have increased due to improvement in economic activity, progress in the pass-through of cost increases to selling prices, and the yen's depreciation. Meanwhile, the labor share seems to have declined recently (Chart 9). Although a pass-through of higher raw material prices to selling prices is necessary to secure corporate profits, price rises due to this pass-through mean an increase in the burden of households. In order for the economy to see a sustained recovery led by domestic demand and for the virtuous cycle between wages and prices to intensify, it is essential that the increase in corporate profits lead to improvement in household income.

Therefore, in terms of price setting, the key is whether firms will be able to reflect increases in costs besides raw material costs, such as wages and indirect costs, in selling prices. If firms cannot reflect wage increases in selling prices to a certain extent, the virtuous cycle between wages and prices will not last long. On this point, attention should be paid to the fact that the year-on-year rate of increase in prices of services, for which labor costs account for a large share in total costs, has gradually accelerated recently. However, what we have heard from firms gives me the impression that many of them still consider it difficult to pass on higher labor costs to selling prices (Chart 10). Recently, the government formulated guidelines on price negotiations for an appropriate pass-through of labor costs, and its impact on firms' price-setting behavior warrants attention.

The Bank's Thinking on the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Next, I will briefly explain the Bank's thinking on the conduct of monetary policy given the wage and price developments just described. To this day, the Bank has patiently continued with monetary easing while striking a balance between its positive effects and side effects. This policy response may seem in contrast to responses taken by central banks in the United States and Europe, which had raised policy interest rates substantially to address the rapid increase in inflation.

The most significant factor behind the difference in policy responses between these central banks and the Bank of Japan is the divergence in the situation surrounding prices and wages. The central banks in the United States and Europe had taken a wait-and-see approach when prices began to rise, based on the assessment that the rises were "frictions" associated with the resumption of economic activity following the pandemic. Thereafter, however, with further upward pressure on wages, for which developments had been generally consistent with the 2 percent inflation, they became vigilant against the risk of a wage-price spiral and thus significantly raised their policy interest rates. On the other hand, as I emphasized earlier in this speech, Japan had remained in a situation where wages and prices did not move. In order to turn the situation around and achieve sustainable and stable inflation accompanied by wage increases, the Bank of Japan has patiently continued with monetary easing.

That said, if the virtuous cycle between wages and prices intensifies and the likelihood of achieving the price stability target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner rises sufficiently, the Bank will likely consider changing its monetary policy. Given the uncertainties surrounding economies and financial markets at home and abroad, the timing of a policy change is yet to be decided. The Bank will carefully examine economic developments as well as firms' wage- and price-setting behavior, and thereby decide on future monetary policy in an appropriate manner.

III. The Future: Price Stability, Firms, and the Economy

Moderate Inflation and Room for Policy Responses

So far, I have looked back on the past and talked about recent changes in the wage and price situation in Japan. Now, I will turn the clock forward to the future. By "future," I'm referring to a state in which the virtuous cycle between wages and prices will have been achieved. I would like to consider what this cycle would mean to firms and Japan's economy as a whole.

In standard economics, the most obvious benefit of a slightly positive inflation rate is larger room for monetary policy responses to an economic downturn. The primary transmission channel of monetary easing is lowering interest rates to stimulate economic activity. When inflation continues to be 0, nominal interest rates accordingly are low and there is little room for reducing them further. In contrast, in a state in which the inflation rate continues to be positive, nominal interest rates are higher, providing room to substantially lower interest rates if necessary. It is considered that conducting monetary policy effectively reduces the risk of the economy deteriorating significantly or reverting to deflation. This view is widely accepted around the world, and I believe that greater economic stability as a result of securing room for monetary policy responses will have a significant positive effect on firms as they formulate their business plans.

Effects on Resource Allocation and Other Factors

Moreover, based on Japan's experience, I think that, if wages and prices start to move, this will likely add to the positive effect just mentioned on the overall economy.

As I have explained today, a key feature of the low-inflation environment that Japan fell into was the strong bias toward the status quo in wage- and price-setting behavior, which resulted in prices of many items being unchanged. This meant that relative prices between individual goods were less likely to change and the market's price discovery function was less effective. As a result, it may have become inefficient to allocate resources, which may have led to reduced productivity of the economy as a whole. The same is true for wages. While I believe that it was important to maintain employment during difficult times by freezing base pay and cutting bonuses, if a situation where wages do not increase easily continues even after these difficult times pass, the allocation of labor and changes in the wage system will become static. If the situation becomes such that wages increase every year, this could lead to more efficient allocation of labor through setting wages flexibly. In this regard, changes have been seen recently as the labor market has tightened, such as an increasingly active labor market for regular employees looking for new jobs. These developments are also expected to benefit the economy as a whole, as they promote the appropriate allocation of human resources to areas where they are most needed.

Impact on Firms' Behavior

So, how will this movement in wages and prices affect the business community?3 As part of its review of monetary policy from a broad perspective, which was initiated this spring, the Bank of Japan is currently conducting a large-scale survey of firms. In the survey, it is asking firms about whether and why a state in which wages and prices move or do not move is preferable for them, as well as common questions regarding their views on corporate behavior over the past 25 years and recent changes in this behavior. Many of the firms represented by you have also participated in the survey, and I would like to thank you for your cooperation.

While the Bank aims to understand the views of the business community through such dialogue, one possible hypothesis at this time is that, in a state in which wages and prices move in general, it will be easier for individual firms to do so as well. For example, if wages and prices move, it may be easier than in the past for firms to be more flexible in their wage and price setting and their product strategies when formulating business plans. There is no shortage of issues and topics for firms to address, such as digitalization and labor saving amid the expected continuation of labor shortages, decarbonization and other climate change responses, and strengthening supply chains. In this new environment, if firms take these issues as a business opportunity and show a higher tendency to move proactively, the positive impact should permeate throughout the economy.

Of course, the shift to a state in which wages and prices move will present new challenges for firms. Whether it is recruiting and retaining employees or developing pricing and product strategies, firms may need to find different approaches than what they have taken thus far, including investment in new groups of people and resources. I strongly hope that firms will take full advantage of the benefits that should arise in a state in which a virtuous cycle between wages and prices is achieved, and that they will strengthen their positive moves.

  1. 3While there are not many theoretical or empirical studies examining this effect, one example is a series of studies by Professor Watanabe Tsutomu of the University of Tokyo on the effects of low inflation and a deflationary environment on the economy and firms' behavior. See, for example, Watanabe, T. and Watanabe, K., "Defure-ki ni okeru kakaku no kochokuka: Gen'in to gan'i," Bank of Japan Working Paper Series, no. 16-J-2 (February 2016) (available only in Japanese).

Concluding Remarks

The time for my speech is running out. Today, I talked about the past, present, and future of the wage and price situation in Japan.

I would like to conclude my speech by turning the clock to the present again. Firms' wage- and price-setting behavior is changing and the likelihood of achieving the price stability target of 2 percent in a sustainable and stable manner is gradually rising. In order to ensure these developments, the Bank has patiently continued with monetary easing, aiming to facilitate a favorable environment for wage increases. Going forward, it will carefully examine economic developments and closely monitor whether the virtuous cycle between wages and prices will intensify -- in other words, whether wages will be raised in reflection of price rises and such wage increases will be reflected in selling prices. By doing so, the Bank aims to appropriately assess whether the price stability target has been achieved in a sustainable and stable manner.

Thank you very much for your attention.